DOC PREVIEW
MSU EC 201 - Chap2

This preview shows page 1-2-23-24 out of 24 pages.

Save
View full document
View full document
Premium Document
Do you want full access? Go Premium and unlock all 24 pages.
Access to all documents
Download any document
Ad free experience
View full document
Premium Document
Do you want full access? Go Premium and unlock all 24 pages.
Access to all documents
Download any document
Ad free experience
View full document
Premium Document
Do you want full access? Go Premium and unlock all 24 pages.
Access to all documents
Download any document
Ad free experience
View full document
Premium Document
Do you want full access? Go Premium and unlock all 24 pages.
Access to all documents
Download any document
Ad free experience
Premium Document
Do you want full access? Go Premium and unlock all 24 pages.
Access to all documents
Download any document
Ad free experience

Unformatted text preview:

Krugman and Wells Chapter 2ModelsModelsProduction Possibility Frontier (PPF)Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)Opportunity costOpportunity costOpportunity costSlide Number 9Economic growthThe PPFGains from specialization/tradeGains: exampleGains: exampleGains: exampleGains: example Gains: exampleGains: exampleGains: example Gains: lessons for int’l tradeCircular Flow DiagramCircular Flow: 2 types of marketsPositive vs. normative economicsWhy do economists disagree?Krugman and Wells Chapter 2 Steven J. Haider EC201 Spring 2015p2 Models  Models are simplified representations of reality  They can help us focus on important parts of a problem  A model useful for one purpose may not be useful for another  Example: a map  The map would be useless if it were not simplified This map is good for getting to Kalamazoo, but bad for getting to Stockbridgep3 Models  Economic models tend to be mathematical  We can make precise statements about the model  We can use models to help us think about real life situations  Key word is can—it depends on whether the model includes the important pieces  Models can help us focus on one piece of a problem at a time--“all else equal” or “ceteris paribus”  Two common pitfalls to using economic models  Mistaking the model for reality—the model may not apply  Dismissing all models as being “wrong”—of course the assumptions are “wrong”, but that doesn’t mean the model is uselessProduction Possibility Frontier (PPF)  Our first model!  Set-up: Boeing can produce Dreamliners and smaller jets each year  Some example production levels PPF provides the trade-off p4Production Possibility Frontier (PPF)  Concepts  Feasible vs. infeasible quantities  Efficiency  Technology  Opportunity cost… See next slide p5Opportunity cost  Opportunity cost: what must be given up for something else  Consider moving from A to B  A: 15 DL & 20 SJ  B: 9 DL & 28 SJ Thus, to move from A to B, one gives up 6 DL for 8 SJ  “From A to B, the opportunity cost for 8 SJ is 6 DL” p6Opportunity cost  We often talk about OC in terms of 1 unit  A: 15 DL & 20 SJ  B: 9 DL & 28 SJ Or, 6 DL = 8 SJ  1 SJ = 6/8 or 3/4 DL 1 DL = 8/6 or 4/3 SJ  Between A & B  The OC of 1 SJ is 3/4 DL (from A to B)  The OC of 1 DL is 4/3 SJ (from B to A) p7Opportunity cost  From B to A  6 DL = 8 SJ 1 DL = 8/6 or 4/3 SJ  From A to (0,30)  15 DL = 20 SJ 1 DL = 20/15 or 4/3 SJ  From (40,0) to B  9 DL = 12 SJ 1 DL = 12/9 or 4/3 SJ  OC for 1 DL is always the same! p8 Why is OC constant?  PPF is a straight line  OC is just the slope = ΔY / ΔX (negative)  The slope is constant  Generally, we think OC increases  Bowed out (Fig. 2.2)  First 20 SJ costs 5 DL, second 20 SJ costs 25 DL  Why? Some resources may be better suited to SJ than others: size of factory p9Economic growth  Economic growth: shift out of the PPF  Potential causes of economic growth  Increases in factors of production (e.g., pop growth)  Technological growth (e.g., more automation) p10The PPF p11 The PPF is a very simplified model (just two goods), but it has allowed us to precisely define and consider efficiency, opportunity cost, and economic growthp12 Gains from specialization/trade  Suppose there were two countries, US and Brazil, each of which produce two goods, large jets (LJ) and small jets (SJ)  Can they gain from specializing, and then trading?  If one was particularly skilled in LJ and the other in SJ, it would seem the answer is clearly yes Powerful insight: there are gains even if one of the two countries is more highly skilled in both  In economic jargon, absolute advantage doesn’t determine whether trade is beneficial  What matters? comparative advantage  We will work through an example firstp13 Gains: example  The technology (Fig 2.4)  The US is better at producing LJ and SJ than Brazil  In other words, the US has an absolute advantage in producing both  Note assumed consumption levels without trade (both are efficient): US at (16,18) and Brazil at (6,8)p14 Gains: example  Suppose they specialize and then trade—the result  Without trade, both consume what they produce  With trade, I propose levels of production that are consistent with PPF (see previous slide)  Total consumption always equals total production (i.e., the total consumption is feasible given production) Both are consuming bundles outside their PPF (more SJ and LJ)p15 Gains: example  Both are consuming bundles outside their PPF (more fish and more coconuts)  US gains 2 LJ and 4 SJ Brazil gains 2 LJ and 4 SJ With specialization, both US and Brazil achieved a level of consumption that was infeasible (outside the PPF) without tradep16 Gains: example  How does this work?  First, verify that opportunity costs below match Fig 2.4  The US has a comparative advantage in producing LJ because there is a lower opportunity cost: 4/3 < 3  The US gives up 4/3 small jets for each large jet, but Brazil gives up 3  Brazil has a comparative advantage in producing SJ because there is a lower opportunity cost: 1/3 < 3/4  Brazil gives up 1/3 large jet for each small jet, but the US gives up 3/4Gains: example  NOTE: don’t make this harder than it needs to be.  Does the US look relatively better than Brazil in SJ or LJ? That’s the product we have the comparative advantage in….  And Brazil must have the comparative advantage in the other product p17p18 Gains: example  How does this work? (continued)  In the trade laid out below, the US gave up 10 large jets for 20 small jets  The US is willing to do this: we get 2 SJ for each LJ we give up, but if we produced on our own, we would only get 4/3 SJ for each LJ we give up  Brazil is willing to do this: they get 1 LJ for every 2 SJ they give up, but if they produced on their own, they would need to give up 3 SJ for each LJGains: example  Some things to note:  The US has an absolute advantage in both goods  We can produce more SJ and more LJ than Brazil  US and Brazil both gain from trading with each other  We both consume something that was previously infeasible  Both specialized in the production of the good for which they have a comparative advantage  US had lower OC in LJ production, so we


View Full Document

MSU EC 201 - Chap2

Documents in this Course
Load more
Download Chap2
Our administrator received your request to download this document. We will send you the file to your email shortly.
Loading Unlocking...
Login

Join to view Chap2 and access 3M+ class-specific study document.

or
We will never post anything without your permission.
Don't have an account?
Sign Up

Join to view Chap2 2 2 and access 3M+ class-specific study document.

or

By creating an account you agree to our Privacy Policy and Terms Of Use

Already a member?