CU-Boulder ECON 4999 - “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate

Unformatted text preview:

Craig Douglas Econ 4999 “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate One of the tasks that we ask governments to perform on society’s behalf is to allocate public resources in such a way as to maximize their returns. In principle, this is done by evaluating the costs and benefits over time of the possible allocations and choosing the one whose present value is highest. A critical aspect of this process is the choice of a discount rate that accurately reflects the time preferences of society. For short term allocations or investments the discount rate approximates the market rate of return to capital which is the opportunity cost of the investment, modified by some estimate of productivity growth. For very long term investments, specifically ones that span multiple generations, the selection of a discount rate can be more difficult because there is greater uncertainty about both these base rates and because there is a distributional ethics component that is not quantifiable. One possible method for selecting a long term discount rate (LTDR) is to “reverse engineer” it by simply measuring society’s current aggregate willingness to pay (WTP) for intergenerational benefits and then calculating the implied discount rate. Discounting When an individual, or society as a whole, makes decisions about how to allocate resources there is usually a time component to the decision. That is, the allocation results in costs or benefits that accrue some time in the future. In these cases the decision process involves weighing the costs and benefits according to when they occur. All else being equal, most individuals would prefer that benefits occur sooner rather than later, and that costs occur later rather than sooner. The summation of the costs and benefits after accounting for our time preferences is called the present value of the allocation. The rate we assign to the diminution of future costs and benefits is called our discount rate. The process of calculating our discount rate can be broken down into two fairly distinct conceptual exercises depending on the time frame being considered. In the shortterm, realization of costs and benefits comes soon enough that our primary guide in discounting them is the evaluation of the private trade-offs we face when foregoing opportunities across time. In addition to the returns we receive from alternative allocations, these trade-offs involve how risk averse we are and our marginal utility function. As the time frame expands, and particularly when it spans multiple generations, evaluation of private trade-offs becomes problematic because some or all of the benefits our choices create are postponed beyond our ability to personally enjoy them. In this long term situation the calculus of private time preferences yields a present value of zero for benefits that are not enjoyed by the decision makers. Some of the decisions society faces, however, clearly fall into the long term category. For example, we must decide the merits of reducing green house gas emissions, continuing to produce nuclear waste, and saving endangered species habitat, all of which produce costs or benefits that extend far into the future. The implication of personal discounting, that benefits not personally received have no present value, is counter-intuitive. Most individuals would be willing to incur some cost to generate a specific future benefit even if they could not share in it. So where does that present value derive from and at what rate must they be discounting? An LTDR that is purely intergenerational in scope measures society’s sense of distributional equity across generations. This social sense of fairness is different for each of us in the same way that our private preferences differ and derives from our belief systems developed over time. Assuming that an individual’s private valuation of long term benefits is zero, any positive valuation of long term benefits is a reflection of that individual’s social discount rate. By aggregating our collective present valuations of specific long term investments, such as green house gas mitigation, we could work backwards to construct a LTDR that estimates a composite inter-generational welfare function for society. Method of Aggregation The aggregation could be accomplished through a contingent valuation survey. A random sample of the general population would be selected and asked that they specify, in essence, the amount of consumption they are willing to forgo so that a particular longterm public investment could be made. Each participant would receive as complete a description as possible of the costs and benefits involved with the project, the time at which they would occur, where they would occur, and to whom. Historical rates of productivity growth and returns on capital would be provided. The many risks that would be present would also be communicated. These would include the risk that intervening generations would fail to continue the required rate of investment, the risk that we will mispredict the consumption preferences of future generations, and the great uncertainty involved in forecasting any type of benefits and costs so far into the future. With this background, participants would be asked to respond positively or negatively to estimates of their personal costs if the investment were to be made. The results of the survey would be used in a linear regression to estimate a total WTP for the general population, and from there a LTDR could be calculated using an inverse of the present value function shown in equation (1). PV = B1/(1+r)1 + B2/(1+r)2 +…+ Bt/(1+r)t (1) where Bt is the net benefit accruing in time period t and r is the discount rate. An inverse of this function can be estimated, for example, with equation (2), LTDR = r = (Bt/WTP)1/t –1 (2) where B is the time-weighted mean benefit, t is the year in which the weighted mean benefit occurs, and WTP is the current expression of present value. It is likely that individuals will have a different discounting function, one that may not be smoothly declining, but equation (2) will accurately describe an effective rate as expressed through aggregation. Independent Variables Included in the regression would be independent variables that would assist in understanding how population characteristics influence responses. Some would reveal private valuation components. Others might show


View Full Document

CU-Boulder ECON 4999 - “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate

Documents in this Course
Syllabus

Syllabus

18 pages

Poverty

Poverty

6 pages

Essay

Essay

9 pages

Load more
Download “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate
Our administrator received your request to download this document. We will send you the file to your email shortly.
Loading Unlocking...
Login

Join to view “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate and access 3M+ class-specific study document.

or
We will never post anything without your permission.
Don't have an account?
Sign Up

Join to view “Reverse Engineering” a Long Term Discount Rate 2 2 and access 3M+ class-specific study document.

or

By creating an account you agree to our Privacy Policy and Terms Of Use

Already a member?